Wednesday, April 11, 2012

Leading in a Hyperconnected World

SSIR Opinion & Analysis

With the rise of new digital media platforms and social networks, people are absorbing information at a greater velocity and from a wider set of channels than ever before; they are also using that information in new ways. Anyone with an Internet connection or cell phone can share their ideas, influence public opinion, or even spark a movement for change. Yet while technology and the Internet have evolved rapidly over the last decade, our understanding of what it means to be a leader in this new, networked society has not kept pace.

Leadership has become distributed and collaborative. The new reality is that leaders don't lead alone. We are all part of a much broader problem-solving network, with many high-performing organizations and individuals—public and private—working on different parts of the same problem or even the same part of the same problem. The most influential members of the collaborative are increasingly harnessing new technology to share ideas, get real-time feedback, and build knowledge for the field. Leaders are no longer just steering their own ship; they are helping a network solve problems with the best and most current thinking available. Collaboration is the new competition and the more valuable your contributions are, the greater your influence will be.

Living Cities, a 20-year-old consortium of foundations and financial institutions, has long understood that multidisciplinary problems demand multidisciplinary solutions and that collaboration is key to innovation at any scale. But only recently did we realize the true value of communications in accelerating innovation, adaptation, and, ultimately, change. We have started to radically rethink how we communicate about our work, and the ways that communications can help us lead and drive social change. Here are three recommendations for other organizations interested in undergoing the same process.

Mine all stages of the "knowledge life cycle"

There has long been a bias in philanthropy and social change circles that the only knowledge worth reporting comes after organizations complete their work—when they can share a best practice or success story as a finished product. While that is still important, leaders in today's problem-solving network can benefit from information shared during all stages of development—from an early-stage hunch or idea to an emerging approach that requires more testing. Have you ever gone to a conference and noticed how people tend to congregate out in the hallways, talking long after the panel presentations begin? Why is that? Because leaders today are more eager to hear what their peers are grappling with in real-time than what panelists convey in formal exchanges on topics established months in advance. Leaders want to apply the latest thinking from people they respect to their own work. At Living Cities, we are working to perfect this "rapid knowledge prototyping" by sharing our tacit and implicit knowledge.

Engage continuously, don't transact

Many organizations, including Living Cities, have often approached communications from a transactional point of view—that is, they periodically push out expert information or conclusions through press releases or scheduled events. Today, leaders should base communication strategy on constant engagement—two-way information sharing with people and organizations in their problem-solving network. Digital media in particular allows organizations to share what they are doing and learning as their work progresses, and to receive real-time feedback from new and sometimes unlikely sources that can enhance their work. We recently shared a blog post about a framework we are developing to understand new ways of increasing the use of loans in cities; now, feedback from our network is helping us refine and improve this model.

Let go, decentralize

Late, laborious, and ineffective communication efforts have always frustrated me. While a centralized communications department is sufficient when you need to promote your organization (think transactional), it cannot support rapid and ongoing knowledge transfer. By delegating all communications functions to a single department, we make it harder for the people who know the information best to share it. At Living Cities, we are distributing communication responsibilities across the organization and making it a fundamental part of everyone's job to both think about the emerging knowledge in their own work and the best ways to engage with their network. Another impetus to make this shift came after we created an internal portal to encourage staff to share ideas, ask questions, report out after meetings, and update others on their work. We realized that everyone was already producing a great deal of incredibly valuable content, and it just wasn't going anywhere. By decentralizing our communication efforts, we are creating a culture in which all staff are continually thinking of their role in this broader way, and mining their work for new ideas and insights to share.

Mine, engage, and let go. These three tactics can help adapt yesterday's communications function to today's hyperconnected world, where knowledge is king and collaborative leadership the new normal. Our adoption of this new approach to communication is still in its infant stage, but it has already fundamentally changed the way Living Cities thinks and operates.

 

Coming soon: an SSIR webinar on rethinking your organization's communications.

Sent with Reeder


 (verzonden vanaf tablet)

Monday, April 9, 2012

Lord Growth

Development Horizons from Lawrence Haddad
House of Lords Economic Affairs Committee - Sixth Report: The Economic Impact and Effectiveness of Development Aid

The above report was published on March 20. Here are my reactions to the abstract. Disclaimers: (1) I have only read the abstract, not the entire report and (2) IDS is a recipient of DFID funding. My comments appear in italics after LH. There goes the knighthood.

Abstract

One in five of the world's population still lives on less than $1.25 a day. This poverty is a source of great human misery, and, if effective ways can be found to reduce it which are acceptable to the taxpayers of the developed world, then reduce it we should.

This report is about development aid, and how effective it has been in promoting development and poverty reduction in recipient countries. It examines the Government's plans for a real terms increase of 37% in official aid spending in the four years to 2015. The report does not address humanitarian aid for relief of acute distress following conflict, famine, natural disasters or other emergencies, which is less than 10% of official aid spending.

This inquiry has shown that finding ways to realise the simple ambition of reducing poverty by means of development aid is hugely challenging:

▪ Economic growth is essential if poverty is to be reduced. There is however no agreement amongst experts as to the effectiveness of development aid in promoting growth. Estimates vary from those which suggest that development aid has added about 0.5 per annum to growth in recipient countries to those which suggest that it has had no positive, or indeed negative, effect on growth.

LH: Well, this is a House of Lords Economic Affairs Committee, so we should expect them to focus on economic growth as the route to poverty reduction. I disagree with the statement that economic growth is essential if poverty is to be reduced. Some kinds of economic growth are essential. The kind that generates wealth for the top 10% doesn't do much for poverty reduction. The kind that is the result of plunder of natural resources does nothing for those living in poverty. The kind that wrecks the environment and accelerates global warming does not do anyone any favours in the medium term. This lack of nuance about economic growth is truly worrying and for me puts the credibility of the entire report under the microscope. And estimates will vary about the effectiveness of aid on growth, because growth is not always the key constraint to poverty reduction and aid is working through other routes to reduce poverty.

▪ There is far from universal agreement amongst experts as to what the aim of aid should be. Should it be to maximise economic growth? Should it be to have the maximum effect on poverty? Or should it for example be a tool for ensuring that values such as human rights are spread more widely, or for combating climate change? These objectives are not necessarily in conflict but they do complicate the design of aid policy.

LH: This really surprises me. Nearly every development agency has poverty reduction as its number one goal. This is a real consensus. Sure, we quibble about how to define poverty (money metrics, multidimensional measures, perceptions data etc.) and about the best way to reduce poverty (there must be 1000 different things that can be done) but not about the goal of reducing poverty.

▪ There is little agreement amongst experts as to what forms of aid are the most effective. For example, some of our witnesses thought it important to promote foreign direct investment. Some thought that technical assistance was central while others were keener on large-scale projects designed, for example, to combat disease. Different arguments were advanced for project-based aid, for governmental budgetary support and for large scale infrastructure investment.

LH: This "little agreement" is a recurring theme throughout the report summary. This can be used to portray the aid community as a headless chicken, divided on what to do, but I believe it simply reflects the fact that context matters. In one context, capacity will be the limiting constraint, in another health services, in another infrastructure. There is no generic recipe for poverty reduction, only a long list of ingredients that have been shown to work in some places and at some times. This is where the skills of the politicians, technocrats and civic leaders come into play—in forging alliances that get the balance of politics, capacity and policy right to reduce poverty in their own time and place.

▪ There is disagreement among experts as to what is the best way to channel aid. Some argue for multilateral aid on the grounds that it is better for delivery of large-scale development assistance and reduces the number of different donors which aid receiving countries need to keep informed and involved. Others believe that multilateral aid, including aid through the European Union, can be wasteful and that national aid, at least so far as the UK is concerned, is better controlled. Some emphasise the benefits of channelling aid through NGOs and civil society organisations; others emphasise that such organisations can lack scale, and that competition between them can undermine aid, for example by tempting them to make concessions to corrupt governments to preserve their programmes.

LH: I would agree with this. Each route has its strengths and weaknesses, and a diversity of approaches seems the least risky. More evidence here would be very welcome.

▪ There is also disagreement amongst experts as to whether aid should focus on those countries where poverty is most acute—often "failed" or "failing" states—and those who believe that, without better governance, aid will prove a waste of time or worse.

LH: Yes, agree with this too. We need more evidence to tell us when £xm of aid spent in a fragile context lifts more people out of poverty, sustainably, than £xm of aid spent in a non-fragile context. Notice I say when, not whether. There are no universal answers: disagreement is not a bad thing.

There is disagreement amongst experts as to whether aid is a tool enabling donor countries to combat corruption and bring about internal peace, or whether it tends to feed corruption and sustain damaging internal conflicts.

We are however pleased to report that expert opinion is virtually united in agreement that DFID enjoys an outstanding reputation internationally as an effective aid agent. It has refined the Government's approach to aid over a number of years. Now, under an energetic Secretary of State, it is taking direct action to deal with points made by aid critics by for example, increasing its emphasis on promoting private investment and on containing unrestricted budgetary support.

LH: At risk of sounding like a broken record, it depends on the context. But if there are no internal champions of reform, no matter how few, I believe that aid cannot change the governance dynamic. Aid might be able to support the emergence of these champions but that is a 15-20 year business.

We do make recommendations designed to improve DFID's performance further. In particular we fear that, sometimes, it is pursuing various good objectives—helping fragile states, zero tolerance of corruption, cutting staff numbers—that are likely to prove mutually incompatible.

LH: I have written on these pages before, that (a) having a bigger impact on poverty while (b) working in more fragile contexts with (c) a bigger budget and fewer staff is an awfully tall order. I hope I am proven wrong.

We have not sought in this report to reconcile all these different arguments. We have sought to form a balanced view of aid, which recognises its strengths and weaknesses. And, in particular, we have sought to apply that view to reach a sensible verdict on the future of Britain's aid programme so as to ensure, to the maximum extent possible, that it does what taxpayers expect of it: make people in the least developed countries less poor and less miserable.

Summary of Conclusions and Recommendations (1-28)

1) This report focuses on development aid which is over nine-tenths of official aid spending. It is not about humanitarian aid, which accounts for less than 10% of official aid spending. We fully support humanitarian aid. (para 3)

2) Since private capital flows to developing countries are now so much greater than official aid flows it seems clear that private spending has become a much greater contributor to development than official aid. (para 11)

LH: Agree, but the comparisons may be overstating the case a little. Aid, unlike private capital flows, has an explicit poverty reduction goal.

3) Economic growth is essential to bring about poverty reduction in developing countries. Aid is plainly not the main driver of their growth, since capital and trade flows are so much greater, but it can arguably play a catalytic role. We consider in this report what impact aid makes on recipient countries' growth. (para 18)

LH: Agree that aid can play a catalytic role in bad growth and in good growth. We need to get beyond "growth is good" to "some growth is good and some is not".

4) The difficulties of accurate measurement and attribution, and of assessing what would have happened if no aid had been given, are so formidable that the evidence that aid makes a contribution to growth in recipient countries is inconclusive. (para 32)

LH: Yes, contribution to growth, perhaps, but contribution to poverty reduction, no.

5) Large and prolonged aid programmes can have a corrosive effect on local political systems when the priority becomes to attract aid rather than to solve problems. DFID should pay close attention to the scale and composition of aid programmes to ensure that resource flows do not overwhelm local ability to manage them and undermine systems of governance in recipient countries. They should also support recipient governments' systems of audit and public financial management and have a credible exit strategy. (para 36)

LH: agree. But any resource flow has the power to corrupt—it is all about the governance.

6) We welcome evidence of graduation from aid, or progress towards it, by a range of countries in Asia and Africa. We recognise that any contribution by aid to the economic growth which enables graduation may not have been great. We do not subscribe to the fallacy that because graduation took place after aid, it was even in part because of aid, since many factors such as governance, trade and investment affect growth. It seems likely that all contributed, and that aid's impact was greater where, as in Botswana, Ghana or Kenya, it was a higher proportion of GNP in the early days of development and was delivered in support of a clear strategy for growth. We welcome the Secretary of State for International Development's readiness to move with the times and prepare exit strategies in countries where graduation is near. (para 45)

LH: Don't really understand this paragraph, other than to convey the idea that we need to think about aid exit strategies. This is about the only thing I agreed with in Dambisa Moyo's book.

7) The risks of corruption are greater in weak, unstable or failed states. It is important for donors to ensure that opportunities for corruption are as limited as possible by setting in place systems of audit and control as rigorous as local conditions permit and to withhold development aid altogether where corruption is rife and therefore endangers the effectiveness of aid. In the battle against corruption, to which we return later, accountants are more important than economists. (para 50)

LH: Actually I would say behavioural psychology experts (to set up incentives that deter rent seeking in the first place) and civic leaders (to help make the quantity and quality of delivery more transparent) might be more important than the accountants, who definitely have a role to play, but not a lead one.

8) We recommend that DFID should monitor and report on flows of capital from recipient countries, with a view to reducing aid where there are excessive outflows. We agree with Transparency International that the Government should explore with other G20 countries the scope to discourage illicit capital flight from developing countries. (para 55)

LH: agree

9) Growth seems the most effective remedy for global poverty. We are surprised that the role of growth is not more fully acknowledged in the international community's collective approach to poverty reduction. We recognise that trade, investment and remittances are all much more substantial than aid and more important in driving growth. We accept that accurate measurement of whether or how much aid helps promote growth is not available. But similar difficulties arise over measurement of the contribution to growth of trade, investment and remittances, though their indispensability to growth is undeniable. It is uncertain that aid makes a proportionate contribution. (para 58)

LH: At the risk of repeating myself, the growth-poverty elasticity varies tremendously depending on (1) initial inequality, (2) sector of growth, (3) externalities generated and (4) governance of growth. Growth is not a cure-all. And an absence of certain types of growth is certainly not a kill-all.

10) The risks of failure in aid to fragile states are greater than elsewhere, as is the scope for misuse of aid funds. For the Government's planned increase in aid to fragile states to have any chance of being effective we recommend careful selection of programmes and continuous evaluation of their effect, and a robust anti-corruption strategy. (para 73)

LH: Agree

11) Where security policy and aid policy overlap with the aim of bolstering stability, circumstances are often challenging and outcomes uncertain. Lessons must be learnt from the unrealistic goals set for aid in Afghanistan. In the UK, DFID see the Government's Building Stability Overseas Strategy (BSOS) as a useful aid to decision-making. We agree with Rory Stewart MP who told us that "the liberal imperialist idea ... of creating governance and stability in a post-conflict zone through the application of development aid is mistaken." Decisions on intervention should be carefully weighed on the basis of thorough analysis of local circumstances and realistic and proportionate assessment of what is achievable. (para 74)

LH: The last sentence should apply to all aid and indeed to all public financing.

12) We agree with Lord Jay of Ewelme who told us that aid should complement British foreign policy. The Conflict Pool provides scope for coordinated responses by DFID, the Foreign and Commonwealth Office and the Ministry of Defence to instability and conflict in developing countries in carefully assessed cases. (para 78)

LH: I would like to see a greater overlap of foreign policy and aid policy, but which policy circle should move the furthest depends, it seems to me, on the circumstance.

13) We believe that poverty reduction through economic development should remain the main aim of aid policy. (para 84)

LH: I believe the report has made this position abundantly clear. But what would you expect an Economic Affairs committee to say? I actually think the committee's report argues for poverty reduction though improved governance as the main aim of aid policy.

14) We welcome the Secretary of State for International Development's decision to run down bilateral development aid programmes in 16 countries including China and Russia and to concentrate bilateral aid in 27 countries. (para 85)

LH: I also agree with the increased focus on a smaller set of countries. Aid flows are small and can be spread too thinly.

15) Whatever its merits when it was adopted in 1970, we do not accept that meeting by 2013 the UN target of spending 0.7% (£12bn) of Gross National Income on aid should now be a plank, let alone the central plank, of British aid policy because:

a) it wrongly prioritises the amount spent rather than the result achieved;

LH: Is it really the central plank? It is one way of assessing the commitment of the UK government to international development, and perhaps the most transparent way, but it is not the central plank. It is important to get a balance of targets on inputs, outputs and outcomes. If it is all inputs and outputs aid becomes a bureaucratic exercise, but if it is only outcomes, then it becomes an exercise in claiming too much credit when things go well and avoiding blame when they do not. Accountability is maximized when all three are assessed and linked.

b) it makes the achievement of the spending target more important than the overall effectiveness of the programme;

LH: Possibly, but not having an input target would surely weaken the attribution story on outcomes. We need both.

c) the speed of the planned increase risks reducing the quality, value for money and accountability of the aid programme;

LH: possibly.

d) reaching the target increases the risk identified in Chapter 4 that aid will have a corrosive effect on local political systems.

LH: depends where it is spent, how, who, when etc.

We recommend that the core of aid policy should be choosing and funding the best ways of promoting international development and stability, rather than finding new ways to spend ever-increasing resources. (para 95)

LH: I think we would all agree with this, and I am sure DFID think they are doing the former and not the latter.

16) The Government should therefore drop its commitment to enact legislation to enshrine in British law an obligation on future Governments always to comply with the UN target of spending 0.7% of Gross National Income on aid. It would deprive future Governments of the flexibility to respond to changing circumstances at home and abroad. The Secretary of State has not put forward any case for legislation other than the Government's political commitment to it. (para 96)

LH: tough one this. I would like to see the 0.7 enshrined in law, but the timetable does look like it will require a very large step increase in spending to achieve it and this may well be self-defeating politically and practically. The SoS has gotten himself in a bit of a box on this one. My sense is that as long as good progress is made towards 0.7 then the community will not be too hard on him, but I am probably inviting a stream of invective for even suggesting this.

17) We welcome DFID's reviews of all bilateral aid programmes and multilateral agencies supported by Britain. DFID's renewed commitment to results and value for money is a welcome change in approach, if carried through. (para 98)

LH: Yes, with the proviso that value for money does not = low cost.

18) We welcome DFID's decisions to cease funding to a few ineffective multilateral organisations. But more needs to be done. The evidence we received raised concerns about the quality of aid delivered via the World Bank and in particular the UN Development Programme (UNDP). We would support reducing funding to both organisations, which receive large amounts of DFID money, while a more detailed re-evaluation of their work is carried out. The Government should push for a substantial reduction in the European Commission's aid programmes given its focus on the EU's neighbours rather than poorer, low income countries that are in greater need. DFID must provide impact assessments and regular reports on performance of projects it funds through all multilateral organisations. (para 100)

LH: I am sure DFID will look at this in light of its refreshes of these aid reviews.

19) India's impressive economic growth and technological attainments, and its own aid programme, coexist with widespread, extreme poverty. British development aid to the poorest Indian states may provide a perverse incentive to the Indian government to use less of its own revenue to alleviate poverty. We recommend that the Secretary of State should urgently prepare an early exit strategy from the India development aid programme. (para 104)

LH: I doubt this. From what I have seen in Bihar, it will act as a spur and encouragement.

20) We welcome DFID's decision to halve general budget support by 2014/15. We also welcome the introduction of more rigorous conditions of disbursement. But we are concerned that sector budget support—where the funds are spent in specific areas such as health or education—is to jump 20% by 2014/15 and that much of Britain's funding of multilateral agencies may be used as budget support. Since the risks of misuse of budgetary aid are high, both types of budget support—general and sectoral—should be reduced, not just the general budget support targeted by the Government. DFID should also ensure that less of the aid it provides via multilateral organisations is used for budget support, or withdraw funding from multilateral agencies that persist in focussing on budget support. (para 110)

LH: I don't know what the evidence says here.

21) We welcome the new emphasis on the development role of the private sector, which is essential to the creation of strong and sustained indigenous growth. DFID's own efforts should increasingly concentrate on the ways in which it can help to encourage and sustain private investment. It should not be tempted into interfering unnecessarily in the activities of private companies. The more private sector skills can be embedded within the Department, the more likely its efforts are to succeed, with the prize, at the end of the day, of less taxpayer-funded aid. (para 115)

LH: Agree that a better balance of public and private sector expertise will be helpful, but we must not run the risk of lionizing the private sector. Many NGOs achieve miracles on shoestring budgets—achieving value for money ratios that big companies could only dream of.

22) We recognise the difficult case-by-case judgments on aid delivery which DFID faces in easing the plight of the poorest in countries where oppressive regimes violate human rights. We recommend that DFID should continue to exercise vigilance in ensuring aid does not prop up oppressive regimes, even if they are not conspicuously corrupt in a financial sense. (para 117)

LH: Yes.

23) We recognise the valuable contribution that some NGOs can make to development and agree that DFID should use them in the right circumstances to deliver some of its aid, recognising that the NGO sector cannot substitute in the long run for credible and effective recipient-country governments. We recommend, however, that DFID should be as robust in monitoring proper use of funds by NGOs as it is with directly-delivered resources. (para 124)

LH: Yes, and be equally robust in monitoring the proper use of funds by the private sector.

24) We welcome the Secretary of State's commitment to ensure better 'badging' of British aid. Other donor governments are less reticent. (para 130)

LH: If the focus groups say this helps shore up the UK taxpayer base, then OK.

25) We do not advocate a return to tied aid. But we recommend that DFID should consider with the Department for Business, Innovation and Skills how Britain could derive direct economic benefit from its development aid programmes without worsening quality and effectiveness for recipients. (para 131)

LH: Bit of a thin-end-of-the-wedge one here. I suppose there don't have to be tradeoffs, but I suspect any moves in this direction would end up shortchanging recipients.

26) The planned combination of much higher programme spending, especially in fragile states, with administrative staff cuts seems to risk weaker monitoring of programmes and less rigorous vigilance against corruption. We are not convinced that a cut in DFID staff of the magnitude planned can be reconciled with adequate control of the Department's fast-growing budget, although we welcome DFID's plans to strengthen the front line within a stable headcount overall, which we trust will lessen the risk. We recommend that the Secretary of State should ensure that administrative staff cuts do not hamper his focus on results and in particular the struggle against corruption. (para 136)

LH: Agree. Would like to see the evidence that suggests this can be reconciled.

27) There is corruption in many developing countries. We are greatly concerned by the paltry and implausibly low levels of fraud identified by DFID of little over £1m in its global programmes. Given critical reports of the National Audit Office and the Independent Commission for Aid Impact, DFID must make much more strenuous efforts to improve its detection of corruption, especially given the sharp increases in aid over the next few years. (para 143)

LH: I'm not an expert in this area, but other UK Government departments with big benefit budgets show fraud levels of 1-2% and so we should not be surprised at fraud and corruption levels of £70-80 million (on £7-8 billon), although they should never be tolerated.

28) We recommend that both Parliament and DFID monitor ICAI's own effectiveness closely, and take steps necessary to ensure that both its work and its staffing are sufficient both in quality and in quantity for it effectively to discharge its duties. (para 145)

LH: Quite, who is the watchdog for the watchdog?
Sent with Reeder


 (verzonden vanaf tablet)

Do universities contribute to long run development?

Chris Blattman

The short answer may be yes.

We've been talking about the Industrial Revolution the past week, so we may as well go even earlier "Commercial Revolution", the years from 1000 to 1500 (or so) when Europe awoke from its torpor and both cities and trade began to grow.

Davide Cantoni and Noam Yuchtman test whether medieval universities played any role, looking at the foundation of Germany's first universities after 1386.

We find that the trend rate of market establishment breaks upward in 1386 and that this break is greatest where the distance to a university shrank most.

…Universities provided training in newly-rediscovered Roman and Canon law; students with legal training served in positions that reduced the uncertainty of trade in medieval Europe. We argue that training in the law, and the consequent development of legal and administrative institutions, was an important channel linking universities and greater economic activity.

NBER paper here. Earlier ungated paper here.

Sent with Reeder


 (verzonden vanaf tablet)

Fear of Buying: The Psychology of Renting (Part 5 of 5)

The Big Picture

All last week, we looked at the Housing Recovery theme, challenging the arguments and assumptions of the Residential Real Estate bulls. Last Monday, we began with Debunking the Housing Recovery Story, looking at the huge overhang of Shadow inventory. On Tuesday, it was a Reality Check on Home Affordability. Wednesday, we looked at valuations in the Problem With Home Prices. And on Thursday, we discussed Foreclosures: A Decade Long Overhang.

Today in part 5, we take a closer look at the Psychology of Renting — the factors that have led to a fear of owning homes, and how his may play out in the Housing recovery.

~~~

Way back in 2005, as we were approaching the peak of the Real Estate frenzy, David Leonhardt published an interesting and rather contrarian article, Is It Better to Buy or Rent?. The Pulitzer prize winning business reporter for the New York Times wrote:

"But renting might deserve another look right now. After five years in which rents have barely budged while house prices in New York, Washington, Los Angeles and elsewhere have doubled, renting has become a surprisingly smart option for many people who never would have considered it before."

That was 2005 — since then, the Real Estate market crashed 35% nationally. Rents have risen dramatically. After under building rental units for a decade or longer, Home builders have been increasing the percentage of multi-unit homes and apartments they are constructing. The Architecture Billings Index has risen. Not owning a home has increasingly become the first choice for many new households.

We have become a Nation of Renters.

Why has this dramatic shift away from the American Dream of home ownership occurred? Some of it is outside of the potential home buyers control — namely, lacking the financial wherewithal of a 20% down payment and/or ability to qualify for a mortgage. But much of it is driven by Psychology — there are very specific fears of ownership that are (at least partially) alleviated by renting:

1. Owning an asset class that is still falling in price;

2. Being stuck with a property you cannot sell;

3. Losing one's job;

4. Impact of rising Interest Rates on prices;

Despite repeated premature calls of a housing bottom from the likes of savvy investors such as Wilbur Ross and Warren Buffett, we have yet to see prices find much stability. (Premature being the polite word for terribly wrong). What we can legitimately observe is that prices are falling more slowly — but that is not the same as bottoming.

Buyer Psychology plays a huge role in this. When it comes to psychology, we are less concerned with what will actually happen and more focused on potential buyers' perceptions and concerns of what could happen. That is what drives their behavior.

Falling Prices: Its my opinion that it is very doubtful home prices will fall another 35%; However, buyer psychology is that after a steep drop, the fear of a continuing price slide remains. The prior drop impacts their behavior in such a way that they behave as if a similar fall is likely. We see very similar behavior in equity investors, who after a 50% drop in prices, fear more of the same. Their reaction is to panic and sell out, forming a bottom.

Most people do not want to own an asset class that is still falling in price. The ability to ignore the downside momentum and buy into the fall is beyond many traders — and potential home buyers.

Inability to Sell: If you are a long term owner, the short term price fluctuations are irrelevant. But if you may need to sell your property over the short run — let's define that as less than 5 years after purchase –  there is a possibility that the home will sell for less than the purchase price. For someone who saved for a decade to build up a down payment, that is a situation to be avoided.

Even worse than the dollar hit is the situation of not being able to sell the house at any price. This is a problem severely underwater owners face. There homes are worth less than their mortgages, and they suffer from a form of economic immobility. Without a banks permission to effect a short sale, they are stuck. The data shows that once a home is more than 25% underwater, the possibility of a WalkAway or voluntary default goes up dramatically. The impact of this default on credit ratings is severe.

Job Insecurity: Some of the Rental Nation psychology also comes from a very legitimate fear of losing one's income. The mass layoffs during the Great Recession and the inability of many people to get another job of comparable salary is a very credible worry. If one were to lose one's job, a home mortgage and sale becomes a burden. The thought process seems to be its is its easier to find a cheaper rental than go through the full process of selling the home under duress.

Rising Mortgage Rates: The last element in the fear of buying is probably the one that potential buyers are least concerned with; its also the one that has the greatest potential impact on transaction prices: Rising interest rates.

Purchasers of homes are mostly concerned with their monthly costs — the amount they must pay in interest & principle, insurance taxes and maintenance. Interest rates are presently near record lows. The likelihood of an increase over the next decade is a very high probability. Rising rates are not usually a positive factor in terms of homes prices.

Indeed, from the 1970s to 2004, rates were in a secular downtrend. That was very supportive of higher home prices. As rates fall, one can carry the same house at the same monthly cost with a higher purchase price. For most of the past 3 decades, interest policy of the Fed has been an ally of home ownership. Today, it is likely a future headwind.

~~~

We have seen more than $6 trillion in owner's equity destroyed since housing peaked in 2006. Look at the Housing market in Japan — its still a mess, more than 2 decades after its 1989 peak.

The negative implications of buyer psychology are still with us. This is a process, one that will take time to heal. A few years of stable prices, an improving economy, and recognition of the many negatives of renting will eventually bring home ownership back into vogue. But that process is ongoing; it may still not resolve itself for any number of years.

We have made some significant progress — but we are not quite there yet.

>

See also:
Rent vs Buy Calculator (NYT)

Sent with Reeder


 (verzonden vanaf tablet)

The struggle to provide mental healthcare

Global development news, comment and analysis | guardian.co.uk

Years of warfare in Mogadishu have taken a toll on the mental health of many citzens, but appropriate care facilities are limited

Along the main road in Mogadishu, traders are busy selling goods, including second-hand T-shirts and jeans to passing customers. You could almost miss Habeb public mental hospital sitting 5-metres beyond the road. It's the only medical institution in Somalia with trained psychiatric professionals.

Through the hospital's rusty main gate, reinforced with barbed wire, there is a faded sign on the wall that says guns, knives and qat (a narcotic leaf popular in Somalia) aren't allowed on the premises.

Standing next to the sign is Abdi Rahman Habeeb, a middle-aged man with an orange-dyed beard and a deep, husky voice. A psychiatric nurse by training, Habeeb moves slowly from one patient to the next, giving medication. He is closely followed by two volunteers.

The compound housing the hospital seems claustrophobic, probably because of the large number of patients. Almost every little space in the compound is occupied.

It is midday, and the sun's intensity has forced some patients to drag their mattresses out of the tin-roof wards, with their crumbling walls and small windows, to sleep under the shade of the trees where it is cooler. Others lay under rusty bits of tin or old pieces of cloth, held up by wooden sticks, a few feet away from an open-air kitchen.

At least 20 new patients are brought in every day, with some transferred to its other facilities elsewhere in the Somali capital. The hospital runs three other institutions in Mogadishu. On the day I visited, 333 patients were being treated in the four facilities.

Even though the hospital is full beyond capacity, no one is turned away. The number of patients can be significantly higher, depending on whether there has been heavy fighting in the city. "When there is heavy shelling, family members escape the city and can't care for the mentally ill, so the patients are left to roam the streets, where we pick them up from," says Habeeb.

In the six years since the hospital opened, it has treated more than 13,000 mentally ill patients. It survives mainly on donations from local businessmen.

Somalia has been without an effective central government since President Siad Barre was overthrown more than two decades ago. As the country descended into civil war, the health sector was completely destroyed.

Thousands fled to neighbouring countries, and those who couldn't escape were left to live with constant shelling and fighting between the different factions. This has affected the mental state of many.

Official estimates of the numbers affected vary. In 2010, the World Health Organisation (WHO) said it was difficult to get a clear picture as data collection was patchy. According to the WHO, 10% of the world's population is affected by some form of mental illness. This figure is believed to double in areas experiencing or prone to conflict, such as Somalia. "No one in Mogadishu is in a stable mental state," says Habeeb, "due to the constant shelling and displacement. How can someone be psychologically healthy when they're going to bed with the sound of mortars ringing in their ears and waking up to the sound of bullets?"

There is an almost equal ratio of male to female patients in the hospital. Most are young, and come from all walks of life – from former preachers to ex-combatants. Some of the young women in the hospital have brought their children, as they have no one to care for them at home.

Halima Hassan Kulmiye, 45, a mother of six children, was deported from Saudi Arabia and has been at the hospital for the past two months.

"She was normal when she came back a few years ago," says Shamsa Ali, a volunteer at the women's section of the hospital. "The mortars didn't only destroy her house but destroyed her mind too."

Some of hospital's work involves educating locals about mental health illnesses. "Somalis don't think mental illness can be cured by scientific methods," says Habeeb. "They go to traditional healers, who tell them it's caused by witchcraft and jinn [supernatural creatures]."

People with mental health problems are stigmatised, discriminated against and socially isolated. They're also subjected to degrading and dangerous practices, such as being restrained with chains.

Mental health isn't integrated into primary healthcare in Somalia.

A short drive from Habeb hospital is country's biggest health centre, Benadir hospital. "We don't treat mad people here, only normal people," a nurse told me.

The war that has been raging for the past 20 years has placed Somalia at the bottom of health studies. The 2001 UN Development Programme's Human Development Report (pdf) ranked Somalia lowest in all health indicators except life expectancy. In its latest report, the country is not even ranked due to the lack of reliable data.

Habeeb has only one wish: "The rest of the country prays for rain, but here we pray for the war to stop so that fewer people will become mentally ill."


guardian.co.uk © 2012 Guardian News and Media Limited or its affiliated companies. All rights reserved. | Use of this content is subject to our Terms & Conditions | More Feeds

Sent with Reeder


 (verzonden vanaf tablet)

Kotok: I’m Worried

The Big Picture

I'm Worried
David R. Kotok
April 8, 2012

~~~

A note to readers.  This 2000-word commentary is a longer-term view; think in terms of years, not months or days.  The essay is not in conflict with the fully invested position currently held at Cumberland. The words reflect my personal thinking only. Some of my colleagues disagree. In my personal view, the future is uncertain (of course) and may be unattractive for the longer-term outlook. In my view, our American political system is failing us.  In my view, we are joining the list of declining world powers.  The framework to support that argument follows.

"The external menace 'You'll end up like Greece, if you do not do this and that' and the internal opprobrium heaped on some categories of taxpayers are very powerful and dangerous instruments to deprive people of their own personal freedoms."  – Vincenzo Sciarretta

My friend Vincenzo is a journalist from Italy.  He is a serious writer and researcher.  He has covered the financial markets and economy of Italy for years.  He and I co-authored a book on Europe during the optimistic period.  If he and I were to write such a book now, it would probably be quite pessimistic.

Vince responded to my recent email series about the downward spiral underway in the euro zone. Readers may find those essays at www.cumber.com. Vince noted my reports from the meetings in Paris and my reference to the upcoming French elections, where the promise of the Socialist candidate is to raise the tax rate on the highest income level to 75%. I will end this commentary with a longer email from Vince, in which he quotes historian Will Durant and discusses the fall of the Roman Empire.

Now to write some thoughts that gnaw at me in the late of the night, when sleep is elusive.

Simply put: I'm worried.

When I get worried, I read and re-read in my library.  I can honestly say that I have had my nose in a thousand of those books.  The library holds many texts by giants.  They wrote about history, economics, and finance.  They took the strategic view. George Akerlof, Jared Diamond, Niall Ferguson, Carmen Reinhart & Ken Rogoff, Robert Shiller, and Nassim Taleb are among the modern writers.  Milton Friedman, Martin Gilbert, Friedrich Hayek and his polar opposite John Maynard Keynes, Ludwig von Mises, R.R. Palmer, and Adam Smith are among the classics.

A favorite of mine is Paul Kennedy.  Twenty-five years ago, this Yale historian concluded his monumental work The Rise and Fall of Great Powers with a profound observation:

"In the largest sense of all, therefore, the only answer to the question increasingly debated by the public of whether the United States can preserve its existing position is 'no – for it simply has not been given to any one society to remain permanently ahead of all the others, because that would imply a freezing of the differential pattern of growth rates, technological advance, and military developments which has existed since time immemorial."

Kennedy then argued that the United States has the ability to moderate or accelerate the pace of decline.  Such is also the case for other great powers, many of which are in a state of decline from their centuries-old power peak. Among others in his treatise, Kennedy's history lessons examine Spain, France, Rome, and the Austro-Hungarian Empire.

I think I just covered a lot of the euro-zone geography.

In 1987, Kennedy warned us, "The task facing American statesmen over the decades, therefore, is to recognize that broad trends are under way, and that there is a need to 'manage' affairs so that the relative erosion of the United States' position takes place slowly and smoothly."  He added the additional warning that it not be "accelerated by policies which bring merely short-term advantage but longer-term disadvantage."

Unfortunately, America's leadership has not heeded such warnings.

For decades futurists have complained about the rising use of government debt financing by the United States.  They predicted calamitous outcomes, which did not arrive as expected.  Paul Volcker and Alan Greenspan applied monetary policy in ways that allowed inflation and, hence, interest rates to spend a quarter century in decline. The Volcker-Greenspan era opened with the highest interest rates since the Civil War.  Building on this downward momentum, Ben Bernanke has taken the target short-term interest rate to near zero and held it there.

During the same three decades, the US altered its fiscal policy, first under Ronald Reagan and almost continuously since. (The Clinton administration was the exception.)  Rising deficit financing has been facilitated by falling nominal interest rates.  That combination leads to level, or even falling, aggregate debt service.  You can owe more and more and have smaller and smaller monthly payments.  That is the magic of falling interest rates.  Until they hit the zero boundary.

What happens when the music stops and the chairs are full?  Are we reaching that point in the United States?  It appears we have done so in Europe, certainly in Greece, the eldest of the declining great powers.  We are also getting there in Japan and the UK.  All four confront similar financial straits: zero-bound interest rates coupled with expanding national government debt.

About 85% of the capital markets of the world trade by means of the dollar, yen, pound, and euro.  The G-4 central banks have collectively expanded their holdings of government securities and loans from $3.5 trillion to $9 trillion in just four years.  At the prevailing very low interest rates, the functioning of monetary policy and the role of fiscal policy merge.  Is there any difference between a million-dollar suitcase of one hundred dollar bills and a million-dollar, zero-interest treasury bill?  You need an armed guard to protect the first one.  With the second one, you need to clear an electronic trade in a safe financial institution, not an unsupervised (no more Fed surveillance) Federal Reserve primary dealer like MF Global.  Your earnings on either the cash or the T-bill are the same: you earn zero.  You can use the treasury bill to secure a repo transaction at a near-zero interest rate.  You can use the cash to conduct many types of black-market or gray-market trades.  Is it any wonder that the hundred-dollar bill is so popular?  Isn't it understandable that roughly two-thirds of US currency circulates outside the United States?

Is this a healthy situation?  How long can it persist?  What happens next?  When interest rates eventually rise, what will be the result of this blend of monetary/fiscal policy as its unwinding turns malignant?

Moreover, who then will be the politicians that inherit this mess?  Who will occupy the central banker's chair?

I worry because there is no rationally explained strategic-exit plan in the G4. Not in the US.  Not in Japan.  Not in the euro zone.  Not in the United Kingdom.

I also worry because the direction of taxation is up, if certain politicians continue to have their way. I worry because US business tax rates are now the highest in the entire world.  In addition, I worry because of the increasing power that national governments wield in the mature economies of the world.

Applied power eventually leads to serfdom.

Increasing taxation is a characteristic of a declining great power.

Governments are failing to heed Paul Kennedy's warnings.  They are worsening the longer-term outlook.  The Western world's leaders ignored Kennedy when he wrote "… accelerated by policies which bring merely short-term advantage but longer-term disadvantage."

Zero-bound interest rates are a short-term advantage.  We enjoy them. We profit from them.  We expect them to continue for a while.  They are like the oxygen administered to a very ill patient.  If the patient dies, the oxygen has eased the pain in the terminal phase.  If the patient lives, the lungs have been scarred and need many years of healing and repair.  Today, the patient is receiving oxygen in the G4.  Death is being delayed (Greece) or, perhaps, thwarted (elsewhere in the euro zone, Japan, US, and UK).

We do not know how this will play out.  History only warns us that many of the likely outcomes may be unpleasant.   The authors I cited have articulated their differing and diverse views.  Their conclusions have tended to be in the form of warnings.

Paul Kennedy favors candor.  In his second, exquisite work, Preparing for the Twenty-First Century, he wrote: "Many earlier attempts to peer into the future concluded either in a tone of unrestrained optimism, or in gloomy forebodings, or (as in Toynbee's case) in appeals for spiritual revival.  Perhaps this work should also finish on such a note.  Yet the fact remains that simply because we do not know the future, it is impossible to say with certainty whether global trends will lead to terrible disasters or be diverted by astonishing advances in human adaption."

Of course, we hope for the latter and worry about the former.  History gives us little comfort.

For the time being we shall remain on the sanguine side with regard to this global experiment with increasing debt, zero-bound interest rates, and a monetary/fiscal policy compromise that obfuscates the difference between them.

As long as this persists, it means financial markets do well, stocks rise, risk assets regain favor, bonds with hedges yield results, and cash continues to earn zero return.

That is now.  It may change tomorrow, next week, next month, next year or not for quite some time.  There is no way to know.

For the downside from history we return to Vincenzo's email to me:

Dear David,

"I invite you to read the last few sentences of the below article from The Lessons of History, by Will and Ariel Durant. It is about how the destruction of the Roman Empire through the taxation channel made people 'slaves,' in other words how serfdom emerged.  This is my number one fear for Italy, but I guess France is making the same mistakes, just starting from a lower debt level. You can also find an online version of the book, thanks to Google.

"Rome had its socialist interlude under Diocletian. Faced with increasing poverty and restlessness among the masses, and with the imminent danger of barbarian invasion, he issued in A.D. 3 an edictum de pretiis, which denounced monopolists for keeping goods from the market to raise prices, and set maximum prices and wages for all important articles and services. Extensive public works were undertaken to put the unemployed to work, and food was distributed gratis, or at reduced prices, to the poor. The government – which already owned most mines, quarries, and salt deposits – brought nearly all major industries and guilds under detailed control. 'In every large town,' we are told, 'the state became a powerful employer, standing head and shoulders above the private industrialists, who were in any case crushed by taxation.' When businessmen predicted ruin, Diocletian explained that the barbarians were at the gate, and that individual liberty had to be shelved until collective liberty could be made secure. The socialism of Diocletian was a war economy, made possible by fear of foreign attack. Other factors equal, internal liberty varies inversely with external danger.

"The task of controlling men in economic detail proved too much for Diocletian's expanding, expensive, and corrupt bureaucracy. To support this officialdom – the army, the courts, public works, and the dole – taxation rose to such heights that people lost the incentive to work or earn, and an erosive contest began between lawyers finding devices to evade taxes and lawyers formulating laws to prevent evasion.  Thousands of Romans, to escape the tax gatherer, fled over the frontiers to seek refuge among the barbarians. Seeking to check this elusive mobility and to facilitate regulation and taxation, the government issued decrees binding the peasant to his field and the worker to his shop until all their debts and taxes had been paid. In this and other ways medieval serfdom began."

Thank you, Vincenzo, for this serious response.  Thank you Paul Kennedy for superbly articulating history and issuing clear warnings.  Thank you, dear reader, if you are still with me.  I hope I have provoked some thought.

Now we will seek another night's sleep and hope it is not elusive.

~~~

David R. Kotok, Chairman and Chief Investment Officer

Sent with Reeder


 (verzonden vanaf tablet)

Bitcoin a virtual currency for Africa?

Timbuktu Chronicles
Emily Alpert writes In the LA Times:
image courtesy of MIT Tech Review
If you've heard of Bitcoin, you might be a computer geek. The virtual money aspires to become a universal currency that doesn't depend on governments or banks.

Cutting out the banks results in cheaper transactions, Bitcoin backers say. Online payments pass from person to person without using a bank as the middleman. And unlike electronic payments with ordinary currency, governments can't halt Bitcoin payments, an idea that appeals to libertarians.
Recently:
German software developer and Bitcoin exchange consultant Rudiger Koch (of Intersango) recently at pitched the idea in Nigeria, arguing that Bitcoin has advantages for African countries. Bitcoin has no inflation tax, unlike ordinary cash. It could be spent and shared using cellphones, which are ubiquitous in much of Africa. Cellphone systems that let people transfer money by text message are already used in Kenya. And as the value of Bitcoin increases, Koch argues, Africa would get an infusion of money that could be used to bankroll government investment to provide infrastructure and stimulate the economy.
More here

Sent with Reeder


 (verzonden vanaf tablet)

Jack van Ham over ‘de prijs van nationalisme, angst en gemakzucht, met dank aan Arend Jan’

Vice Versa - vakblad over ontwikkelingssamenwerking

Het debat over het nut van ontwikkelingssamenwerking zit momenteel op een hoogtepunt. Jack van Ham wil een stevig onderbouwd tegengeluid geven aan Arend Jan Boekestijn en consorten. De voormalig topman van ICCO en het Rode Kruis is daarnaast bang dat Nederland 'een mooie toekomst achter zich laat'.

Dat de kogel door de ontwikkelingshulpkerk zou gaan, is geen verrassing. Arend Jan Boekestijn en consorten kregen jarenlang vanwege populistische en spektakeltaal veel mediapodium. Nu lijkt het laatste restje verzet hiertegen verdwenen. In twee jaar tijd wordt het budget van, volgens Boekestijn, "het nationaal schuldgevoel", waarschijnlijk met ongeveer 50% wegbezuinigd.

Het gedoogkabinet haalde er in zijn eerste jaar 900 miljoen euro af. Hierbij reken ik de budgetvervuiling niet mee. In haar tweede jaar moet het gek gaan als ze er niet nogmaals 0,5 tot 1 miljard euro afhalen.

In zijn eentje

'Achter zijn wat groot uitgevallen en ruim gevulde salade' (NRC Handelsblad, zaterdag 31 maart), zat Boekestijn tegenover NRC-redacteur Tom-Jan Meeus toen hij vertelde over zijn verdiensten op het gebied van ontwikkelingshulp voor een interview in deze krant. In zijn eentje sloopte hij 'de linkse kerk' op dit onderwerp. Vanaf dag één dat hij in het parlement kwam, startte hij zijn aanval. Met nimmer een stap in Afrika gezet, wist deze geschiedenisprofessor Nederland te overtuigen dat 'hulp niet helpt' en dat 'hulp afhankelijk maakt' en 'zo spoedig mogelijk gestopt dient te worden'. Met compassie kwam hij de door ontwikkelingshulp gesteunde slachtoffers van verafschuwde corrupte regimes (Congo) onder ogen. Vervolgens beschoot hij als inmiddels oud-Kamerlid de ontwikkelingshulp met sloopplannen vanuit Utrecht.

Dat er bij de rekenmodellen en filosofie van hulpafhankelijkheid kritische vragen kunnen worden gesteld, zal de gemobiliseerde en met succes opererende tegenstanders van hulp weinig schelen. Zij zijn inmiddels ook in de kleinst denkende meerderheid aan het roer van de BV Nederland.

Hoe kunnen onze medewereldburgers, meer dan 1,5 miljard in getal, hulpafhankelijk zijn geworden van 100 miljard euro wereldwijde ontwikkelingshulp? Deze hulp voegt per dag ongeveer een kwartje toe aan het inkomen van 2 dollar per dag. Volgens de doctrine van Boekestijn moeten ze daarmee zelf hun welvaart organiseren en zich tegen corrupte regimes verzetten.

Echte hulpafhankelijkheid

Een afhankelijkheidsrelatie ziet er volgens mij iets anders uit. Bijvoorbeeld als er 2000 miljard euro belastinggeld in banken wordt gestopt die anders omvallen, dat noem ik hulpafhankelijkheid. Maar dat is niet aan de anti-hulplobby besteed. Zij geven liever nog een schepje meer chagrijn over ontwikkelingssamenwerking, over die hulporganisaties die steeds meer afhankelijk zijn geworden van de overheid. En volgens Boekestijn kunnen zij nog nauwelijks op steun vanuit de bevolking rekenen.

Het is tekenend voor hedendaagse politici van zijn kaliber dat ze aan hun kiezers niet meer durven uit te leggen dat zij, gekozen volksvertegenwoordigers, dit soort besluiten decennia lang zelf hebben genomen. Met voldoende meerderheid in de Kamer en dus, volgens de wetten van de parlementaire democratie, met de steun van de bevolking die ze koos. Deze beslissingen gingen destijds boven de waan van de dag uit, maar dat was het lef en het bijzondere van de politiek. Het is een weg die Kamerleden in de huidige internet-poll-politiek niet meer durven te gaan en in plaats daarvan zijn ze zich gaan verschuilen achter de meerderheid van de dag. Onze parlementariërs duiken weg op het moment dat we wat van ze mogen verwachten en laten hun besluiten afhangen van opiniepeilers als Maurice de Hond. Of in het geval van de PVV en VVD, op ons nationale geweten: dagblad De Telegraaf.

Op dinsdag 3 april maakte deze krant weer eens duidelijk aan welke kant van de discussie zij staat. Met chocoladeletters op de voorpagina "beschuldigde" de krant CDA-prominenten (en Bill Gates) dat ze zich laten beïnvloeden door hulporganisaties. Waar de krant dagelijks mensen als Wientjes aan het woord laat om het achterkamertjesberaad in het Catshuis te bestoken, criminaliseren ze mensen die zich druk maken over de publieke zaak en de laatste restjes solidariteit. Op deze manier worden de Nederlandse belangen gespaard, de publieke en mondiale zaak verkwanseld en de positie van Nederland in de wereld vergooid.

Afkoop en verzachting

Laat er geen misverstand over zijn, ontwikkelingssamenwerking is nooit alleen altruïsme geweest. Dit in tegenstelling tot wat Boekestijn en zijn medestanders beweren. Het was en is in veel gevallen de afkoop en verzachting van oneerlijke handelsverdragen, behoud van economische voorsprong en eigenbelang. Het was op goede wijze gericht en gebracht naar landen die nauwelijks op eigen benen konden staan en een steuntje in de rug kregen. In ruil hiervoor bracht het voordelen met zich mee als ruimte, grondstoffen en energie.

Nu we de investeringen in ontwikkelingssamenwerking kunnen verzilveren doordat landen opkomen en meer welvaart krijgen, dan telt Nederland zijn knoopsgaten en niet zijn knopen. Wij draaien ons om en gaan fors bezuinigen in plaats van noodzakelijk beter te investeren in faire en duurzame ontwikkeling, kennisversterking, deugdelijke belasting en rechtssystemen en bestrijding van corruptie.

Geïsoleerd plekje

In plaats van tientallen jaren van voorsprong op vele gebieden als techniek, mensenrechten, educatie en zorg op goede en economische wijze te delen, bezuinigt Nederland waardoor het zich terugtrekt. Met Wilders, de nationale trots van euroscepsis en xenofobie, voorop wordt Nederland het geïsoleerde plekje achter de dijken.

Over tien jaar herinnert niemand zich het durflandje vol lef en initiatiefnemer in Europa. Het landje dat niet te beroerd was om te investeren in compassie en globaliseren. Dat voorop liep in innovatie en een moreel gidsland was.

Dankzij Wilders zal een ondraaglijk zorgsysteem tegen die tijd het bedrag van 100 miljard euro per jaar benaderen. Waar heb ik dat bedrag eerder gehoord? En een hypotheekrenteaftrek die groter is als de overheidsschuld, sleept zich in de achterhoede van de wereldwijde economie vooruit. Nederland laat een mooie toekomst achter zich.

"De prijs van nationalisme, angst en gemakzucht", met dank aan onder andere Arend Jan.

Sent with Reeder


 (verzonden vanaf tablet)